Stagflation is an unusual economic situation in which high inflation (leading to increasing prices) coincides with increasing unemployment rates and decreasing levels of output/stagnation of economic growth. That’s why it’s called “stagflation”: it’s a clear combination of inflation and economic stagnation. Economic stagnation is defined as an extended span of minimal or nonexistent economic growth (generally, that means under 2 or 3 percent growth annually).
What is Stagflation?
The reason stagflation is often described as “unnatural” is that, in most cases, weak economies do not see high rates of inflation. That’s because, in your average market economy, inflation is actually inhibited by low levels of economic growth: the resultant low consumer demand prevents increases in the price of goods and services. Stagflation is commonly triggered by sharp increases in commodity prices.
What Causes Stagflation?
Stagflation has a number of potential causes, including:
- Government expansion of the money supply: When, for instance, governments print currency or central banks’ monetary policies produce credit, the money supply is increased—this leads to inflation.
- Decreasing levels of productivity: When production is less efficient, and productivity falls as a result, output likewise decreases as costs increase.
- Supply-side shock: As described above, increases in the price of commodities like oil likewise increase business costs by making transportation more expensive.
- Increasing structural unemployment: In the case of major technological changes, for instance, decline in traditional industries produces structural unemployment, as well as decreases in output. In these situations, unemployment can be growing even with increasing inflation.
- Central bank raising interest rates: By preventing companies from producing more goods and services, this can slow growth.
- Conflicting contractionary and expansionary policies: In most cases, these reduce economic growth and increase inflation.
- Sudden increases in oil prices: In the 1970s, this increase occurred when the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) instituted an embargo for Western countries. The price of oil worldwide skyrocketed, which caused the cost of goods to increase. As a result, unemployment increased.
- Non-diversified economies in cities: Famous urbanist Jane Jacobs believed that stagflation could be prevented with an emphasis on “import-replacing cities” in which production and imports were balanced. In other words, diversifying city economies could benefit the economy enough to inhibit stagflation.
The Phillips Curve and Stagflation
Keynesian economics produced the Phillips Curve, a macroeconomic theory positing a trade-off between inflation and unemployment. With the Great Depression looming large in recent history, economists in the 20th century feared deflation while believing that inflation-lowering policies made life harder for unemployed people. They believed, too, that policies created to mitigate unemployment would produce higher inflation. But the stagflation of the mid-twentieth century complicated things by showing that this rule wasn’t true across the board. (And more broadly, it demonstrated how economics-in-practice can contradict and undermine even dominant economic theories.)
A standard Phillips Curve shows a trade-off between unemployment rates and inflation rates. As shown in the graph above, stagflation pushes the Phillips Curve to the right and worsens this trade-off: with stagflation added to the mix, there are higher rates of both unemployment and inflation.
The History of Stagflation
After the mid-twentieth century, and particularly during the 1960s and 1970s, stagflation gained wider recognition as a serious problem. The term “stagflation” itself was coined by U.K. politician Iain Macleod in the 1960s, during a speech in the House of Commons. He was describing the United Kingdom’s “stagnation situation,” in which there was a combination of stagnation and inflation.
Later on, at the time of the oil crisis, the price of oil increased threefold in the 1970s and stagflation resulted. The U.S. experienced a recession, with five quarters in which GDP growth was negative. In 1973, the rate of inflation doubled; by 1975, the rate of unemployment reached 9 percent.
As described in the previous section, stagflation moves the Phillips Curve further to the right on the graph. This stagflation-induced shift as it manifested in the case of the United States economy in the 1970s. With higher inflation as well as higher rates of unemployment, the trade-off had worsened.
Meanwhile, in the United Kingdom during 1974, there was a 25 percent increase in inflation along with not only minimal but negative GDP growth. This situation was produced by the tail end of the Barber Boom (itself created by the 1972 budget of Conservative politician Anthony Barber) as well as the increase in oil prices, as was the case in the United States.
There were major changes in inflation and GDP growth in the UK from the mid-20th century, shortly after World War 2, until 2009 (be sure to note the drastic spike in inflation rates in 1974):
During this time, the overriding economic theories of the era (which were popular in academia as well as in the policy world) struggled to account for the causes of stagflation. In fact, these prominent economic theories had incorrectly set up stagflation as an impossibility. (Most notably, this includes the Phillips Curve, discussed in more detail below.)
In the 1970s, the strong presence of stagflation also led Yale economist Arthur Okun to develop the Misery index. This was a straightforward metric that functioned to quantify the misery average people felt in response to stagflation. The Misery index itself is quite simple: it is the sum of the inflation rate and unemployment rate. (In more recent years, the Misery index has now incorporated other numerical indicators, including the lending rates of banks.)
Stagflation in More Recent Decades
Since the economic chaos that peaked in the 1970s, inflation has been a normal situation, even at times when economic growth has been minimal or negative. And in the last half-century, all US recessions have involved steadily increasing consumer price levels.
Although not as serious as that of the 1970s, some stagflation also took place during the 2008 Great Recession, when oil prices increased. The Fed used expansive monetary policies in response to this economic downturn.
How to Address Stagflation
There are a number of possible responses that can be used to effectively mitigate stagflation. None are absolutely foolproof, nor are they typically simple to implement. They are useful, however, so we will describe them here:
Lower Dependency on Oil
Based on economic history (much of which we’ve described so far), we know that high oil prices contribute significantly to stagflation. Thus, it stands to reason that minimizing an economy’s dependence on oil can help lower the risk of stagflation. Such an energy transition also has the additional, much-needed benefit making the economy and society as a whole more sustainable.
Supply-side Policies
Supply-side policies can increase productivity in order to facilitate higher levels of growth, while the risk of high inflation remains low.
Monetary policy
A central bank (such as the Federal Reserve) or other such Institution can raise interest rates to lower levels of inflation. They can also lower interest rates to contribute to greater economic growth. This approach has limited in that monetary policy is unable to address a simultaneous recession and inflationary issues.
The Risk of Future Stagflation
2011 saw the public afraid of the possibility of a new, economically disastrous period of stagflation. This fear arose in response to the Fed’s expansionary monetary policy, which had been used as a strategy to respond to the 2008 financial crisis.
Likewise, Congressional approval of an expansionary fiscal policy included high deficit spending and a major economic stimulus package. Combined with economic growth of just 1 to 2 percent, this situation raised fears of stagflation, which could occur if the economy continued to stagnate as inflation persisted.
Notably, though, the government strategy of increasing global liquidity functioned to inhibit deflation, which is, in fact, a much more serious risk to the health of the economy than high levels of inflation. The Fed was watchful that inflation did not exceed the core inflation rate target of 2 percent. Had inflation exceeded that target, they would have responded by instituting a monetary policy that was constrictive rather than expansionary.
Here is the good news: although stagflation was an undoubtedly significant economic problem in the 1970s, the context that produced it most likely will not arise again. There are three major reasons why stagflation is likely to remain a thing of the past:
- We are no longer on the gold standard: During the 1970s, the dollar was removed from the gold standard; assuming we never switch back to the gold standard (which is extremely unlikely), it’s fair to say that this removal will not need to happen again.
- Wage price controls are not used in the same way: Those in power have learned not to use wage-price controls to constrain supply in the same way as they did in the past when stagflation occurred.
- The Fed’s stop-go monetary policies no longer prevalent: Very importantly, the Fed does not use stop-go monetary policies anymore, which makes a major difference in the likelihood of future stagflation.
The session was good to watch and I am a big fan of studying Economics. Please let me learn through you